Editor’s Note: This analysis is part of USC-Brookings Schaeffer Initiative on Health Policy, which is a partnership between Economic Studies at Brookings and the USC Schaeffer Center for Health Policy & Economics. The Initiative aims to inform the national health care debate with rigorous, evidence-based analysis leading to practical recommendations using the collaborative strengths of USC and Brookings.
With Republicans now in control of the Presidency, Senate, and House of Representatives, they have the opportunity to fulfill their repeated promise to repeal and replace the Affordable Care Act (ACA). They banded together to pass repeal alone early this year (albeit knowing it would get vetoed by the president), but no detailed consensus replacement plan has emerged.
There has been no shortage of ACA replacement plans put forward by think tanks and members of Congress, including Speaker Paul Ryan’s Better Way, HHS Secretary nominee Tom Price’s Empowering Patients First Act, and the Patient Choice, Affordability, Responsibility, and Empowerment Act (P-CARE) led by Senate Finance Committee Chairman Orrin Hatch, House Energy & Commerce Chairman Fred Upton, and Senator Richard Burr, but many are still in outline form or lack critical details and none has been voted on or scored by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO).
Despite the lack of consensus on what a replacement plan looks like, Republicans are signaling that they plan to use the budget reconciliation process (which only requires a simple majority in the Senate rather than the 60 votes needed to bypass a filibuster) to pass a law immediately that repeals the ACA’s Medicaid expansion, premium tax credits, cost-sharing assistance, and the taxes that helped pay for it (leaving in place the law’s insurance market and Medicare reforms) as of a date certain in the future (likely January 1, 2020). The delayed effective date is supposed to give lawmakers time to craft a replacement without disrupting coverage in the interim.
Repeal and Delay Would Cause Chaos in the Individual Insurance Market
President-elect Trump and Congressional Republican leaders have staunchly expressed their intent to replace the ACA but keep in place some key popular features of the law such as the ban on discriminating based on pre-existing conditions. If replacing the ACA is truly the goal, though, repealing it first without a replacement in hand is almost certainly a disastrous way to start.
First, a reconciliation bill (like the one passed in 2016) would likely destabilize the individual market and very possibly cause it to collapse in some regions of the country during the interim period before any replacement is designed. That’s because some insurers that have stayed in the individual insurance market in hopes of adding customers as they gained experience with the ACA marketplaces would likely pull out of the individual market under the “repeal and delay” scenario, in the face of the law’s uncertain future and thus unpredictable enrollment and costs.
Second, insurers that do remain would be inclined to raise their premiums to account for that uncertainty and because the reconciliation repeal bill would immediately eliminate the individual and employer mandates that help increase enrollment of healthier people. CBO estimates that eliminating the individual mandate would alone increase premiums by 20%. This combination, in turn, would cause a substantial number of those currently with insurance, especially younger healthier ones, to drop their insurance, leaving an even sicker risk pool in place and increasing premiums even further.
Researchers at the Urban Institute estimate that the market destabilization caused by “repeal before replace” would increase the number of uninsured by 4.3 million people near immediately.
To avoid this result, Republicans would need to devote additional money to stabilizing the ACA’s marketplaces, through such measures as bringing back limits on insurer losses and profits (known as “risk corridors”) and subsidized reinsurance (which helps cover the costs of the most expensive enrollees). However, Republicans spent the last few years decrying these measures as “insurer bailouts,” and suing to stop the law’s cost-sharing subsidies.
Political Hurdles to Replacing the ACA
Even if lawmakers can agree on spending money to stabilize the market during the “delay” period, there’s no guarantee that a replacement plan will garner sufficient support to pass Congress. A reason for this is that any replacement reforms will require some level of bipartisan backing to get past a filibuster in the Senate, which requires 60 votes (Republicans will only control 52 seats, at least until 2019), and probably to hold a sufficient number of Republicans in the House of Representatives (where some may balk at the cost of any suitable replacement).
Starting with repeal also makes replacement more difficult by eliminating $680 billion (over ten years) worth of taxes on high-income households and the health care industry that helped pay for the ACA’s coverage expansion. Even incorporating the dynamic effects of ACA repeal (CBO estimates that ACA repeal would slightly increase economic growth, and in turn revenues), the reconciliation bill passed in 2016 would have saved $516 billion on net over ten years, leaving only roughly half the amount spent by the ACA to pay for replacement coverage provisions. Moreover, given that the costs of repealing the ACA’s taxes, and the so-called Cadillac tax in particular, grow faster than the savings from eliminating the coverage provisions, the reconciliation version of repeal would actually increase deficits in the long run.
Lawmakers could generate some additional revenue by capping the tax exclusion for employer-provided health insurance, as many of the Republican replacement plans propose, but unless the cap were set significantly lower than that of the ACA’s Cadillac tax, such a policy would not raise much more than $100 billion over ten years. It could raise more if the cap were set lower or gradually lowered over time, but given how difficult the Cadillac tax has proven to sustain, doing so would not be easy.
Consequences of Repealing Without Replacing– “Death Spiral” in the Individual Market”
If no replacement plan materializes, the hollowed out individual market – for people without access to employer-provided or public coverage – could be left in shambles. Because reconciliation is a process intended only to modify provisions that directly impact the budget, repeal through reconciliation will eliminate the Medicaid expansion and subsidies to buy private insurance, for instance, but likely leave the ACA’s insurance market regulations in place.
With the ACA regulations that ban insurers from denying coverage or charging higher premiums based on pre-existing conditions remaining, but without the law’s significant subsidies or mandates, the individual market is very likely to enter a “death spiral.” Without subsidies or the individual mandate, many healthy people will exit the market and choose to go uninsured, which will cause insurers to raise premiums further to account for the now sicker, on average, enrollment, which in turn will cause more and more healthy people to rescind their coverage, and premiums to rise further.
And this expectation isn’t just theoretical. The insurance market in New York before the ACA illustrates roughly what happens when insurers have to offer coverage without subsidies but cannot charge differential premiums based on health status – extremely high premiums and extremely low enrollment. In this situation, people without access to employer or public coverage would be left without affordable insurance options.
How Many People Will be Affected?
A death spiral in the individual market would harm more than just the 9.4 million beneficiaries of the ACA premium subsidies.
Under the ACA, the number of people who purchase insurance through the individual market has grown from roughly 10.5 million before the law to about 18 million people today, roughly half of them purchasing insurance off the exchanges. Full repeal of the ACA, then, would be expected to shrink health coverage through the individual market roughly back down to 10.5 million.
But delayed repeal with the hope of replacement, which eliminates the ACA’s subsidies and mandates but leaves in the place the ACA’s insurance regulations, risks nearly destroying the individual market altogether if no replacement emerges. In its wake, only 1.5 million people would get health insurance through the individual market, 9 million fewer than before the ACA, according to estimates from the Urban Institute and fitting with the experience in New York before the law. A small number of people would instead get coverage through an employer.
Therefore, partial repeal of the ACA through reconciliation would leave even more people uninsured than before the ACA’s passage.
CBO estimates that ACA repeal, including the regulations, would cause 22 million people to lose insurance coverage, but they make clear that the effects would be worse if the law’s insurance regulations remained in place. The Urban Institute estimates that an additional 7.3 million would lose insurance coverage under partial repeal, for a grand total of nearly 30 million people newly uninsured.
Even if repeal through reconciliation is able to eliminate the ACA’s insurance regulations simultaneously, which some have argued is possible, that still would leave in its wake over 20 million uninsured. Unless Congress left intact the ACA’s restrictions on pre-existing conditions and guaranteed issue insurance regulations, it would also mean going back to the individual market that existed before the ACA where people could and did get rejectedfor coverage based on a multitude of pre-existing conditions, or had coverage rescinded when they became sick.
Insurance industry estimates from 2008 found that 13% of people who applied for coverage in the individual market were rejected outright, as were 29% of people aged 60-64. And these figures don’t even include the numerous people who didn’t bother applying because they knew they would be rejected, as a result of prior rejections or a broker’s advice, or the 34% of people offered a policy only without coverage for their pre-existing condition or at significantly higher than standard rates.
What an ACA Replacement Plan Should Focus on
If replacing the ACA with something better is the goal, as President-elect Trump and Congressional Republican leadership have indicated, then repeal should happen simultaneously with replacement. Fortunately, President-elect Trump has indicated a desire not to repeal without a replace plan in-hand, and Senator Lamar Alexander (chairman of the powerful Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions Committee) has also expressed a preference to “replace then repeal.”
In taking a different direction, a replacement plan should also focus on fixing the key problems currently facing the ACA: insufficient incentives for the young and healthy to buy coverage; risk adjustment and adverse selection challenges; a lack of competition in many regions; and the unpopularity of the individual mandate.
Taking this approach, a workable replacement plan that might be acceptable to the new Congress would:
- Repeal the individual and employer mandates.While doing so in isolation would increase premiums in the individual market (by 20% in CBO’s estimation) to the extent that healthier people then choose not to enroll in coverage, other regulatory policies could help offset this impact, although well-structured subsidies would also be needed. For instance, late enrollment penalties could be added, auto-enrollment could be pursued to the extent possible (though this is likely impossible to fully administer without better data capabilities), or open enrollment could be made less frequent than once per year. The adverse impacts could also be mitigated by tightening special enrollment periods and the 90-day waiver period before insurers can stop coverage due to non-payment of premiums.
- Introduce a publicly-funded reinsurance or high risk pool program.A publicly-funded reinsurance program would use general revenues to pay for a sizeable percentage of any health insurance enrollee’s costs above a certain amount, similar to the program that operates in Medicare’s prescription drug benefit (Part D). Doing so would minimize the costs and risks to insurers of covering enrollees with very high health costs, whose care accounts for a disproportionately high share of total costs, and in turn would allow insurers to offer significantly lower premiums throughout the entire individual market and make significant losses less likely. Alternatively, federal support for state high-risk pools – proposed by several Republican leaders, including Speaker Paul Ryan (R-WI) – could accomplish a similar goal if the funding level is sufficient. Most high-risk pool efforts to date have fallen short due to inadequate funding.Publicly-funded reinsurance or well-funded high-risk pools would more directly subsidize the costs of the sickest people, whereas the ACA effectively requires healthy people to subsidize the sick (with protection for lower-income people through subsidies), which has proven difficult in the relatively small individual market, particularly in certain localities. Reinsurance or high-risk pools could make it possible to cover sicker individuals while keeping premiums sufficiently low in the individual market to attract healthier people. Either would also lessen the need for ACA premium subsidies to be as high, and would in fact automatically lower them because the ACA’s premium tax credits are tied to premiums as a percentage of income.
- Loosen age rating restrictions in the individual market.Nearly every ACA replacement plan involves widening the age rating bands that currently restrict insurers from setting premiums for the oldest adults in the individual market (64 year olds) that are more than three times the premium they charge a 21-year old for the same coverage. Proposals suggest changing the current 3:1 ratio to 5:1 or 6:1 or eliminating it altogether. Pursuing this reform would have the effect of lowering premiums for younger people and increasing them for older people, making premiums more in line with the actual health costs of each age group and thereby encouraging greater enrollment of younger adults.
- Allow lower actuarial value plans.Currently, the least comprehensive health plans available to everyone in the individual market must have an actuarial value of at least 60% (meaning that they cover 60% of an enrollee’s annual health costs, on average) – so-called “Bronze” plans. Reform could allow insurers to offer lower actuarial value plans, possibly at a 50% actuarial value “Copper” level, which previously received Congressional support and would introduce a cheaper insurance option for people who prefer less coverage. Bronze plans already tend to have rather high deductibles ($5,700 on average), although many services deemed preventative are covered before the deductible is reached. Allowing lower actuarial value plans, therefore, may require also increasing the highest allowed maximum annual out-of-pocket cap (currently $6,850 in 2016 for individual coverage). Allowing lower AV plans can also present difficulties for risk adjustment, although the existence of a publicly subsidized reinsurance program would largely mitigate those concerns. In conjunction with this policy, the required essential benefits that health plans must offer could be simplified to be broader categories rather than specific services in certain cases.
- Limit medical loss ratio (MLR) restrictions.Insurers in the individual market are currently required to spend a minimum of 80% of premium revenue on enrollee health care (and some closely related items), or have an MLR of 80%. New or even small insurers could be exempted from the MLR requirement, as some analysts have suggested, or the MLR could be eliminated altogether in individual markets with at least three insurers, based on the presumption that it’s most needed as a protection against the pricing power of insurers in consolidated markets.
- Loosen restrictions on 1332 state innovation waivers.Section 1332 of the ACA allows states to apply for waivers from many provisions of the law, including the individual and employer mandates and the exchanges, and to redesign the subsides and benefits structure, provided the broad coverage objectives of the ACA are maintained and households are not exposed to greater out-of-pocket costs. The Obama Administration was reluctant to encourage the broad interpretation of this provision. But the new administration could make the waiver guidelines less restrictive and do more to encourage states to take advantage of them, effectively encouraging a state-led federalist approach to replacing much of the ACA.
- Replace the Cadillac tax with a cap on the ESI exclusion.The Cadillac tax takes the first step toward capping the previously unlimited nature of the tax exclusion for employer-provided health insurance, in order to remove incentives to offer high-cost insurance and to generate funding to help pay for subsides for coverage. A straightforward limit on the value of compensation in the form of employer-sponsored health benefits that can be excluded from taxation, though, would accomplish the same goals in a more progressive and economically efficient manner – such a limit could also apply only to employees above a certain income. This policy change has been part of almost every ACA replacement plan and is widely supported by economists of both parties.
If lawmakers wish to go farther, they could also make more expansive changes in the current structure:
- Replace the ACA’s cost-sharing subsidies with income-related contributions to a Health Savings Account (HSA).Taking this approach could achieve the same goal as the ACA’s cost-sharing subsidies, but it would make patients more sensitive to the cost of non-emergency care, could incentivize them to shop around for cheaper alternatives, and provides people a savings vehicle. If this reform is pursued, the tax treatment of HSAs should also be modified to make them more beneficial to lower-income individuals by converting their tax deductibility (which disproportionally helps wealthier people who are in higher tax brackets) to being a refundable tax credit.
- Modify the current income related premium subsidies.Many Republican replacement plans replace the ACA’s income-related premium subsidies with a flat, though age-adjusted tax credit available to everyone. However, it is also important to maintain an income-related subsidy in order to keep health care affordable for lower-income individuals without escalating the total cost of the program. A flat subsidy sufficient to make insurance affordable to a low-income household would give significant money to people who can now easily afford to buy insurance, and would risk undermining the employer-based market. One compromise might be:
- Combine a flat, age-adjusted base level subsidy available to everyone in the individual market with an additional income-related subsidy to keep total expected annual health costs (including both premiums and cost-sharing for an average beneficiary) below a certain percentage of income.
One benefit of combining a universal base level of subsidization with lower actuarial value requirements is that insurers could then be required to offer one plan with a premium precisely at that subsidy level. Even though this plan would likely be little more than a very high out-of-pocket cap, every American in the individual market would at least gain access to some basic level of coverage. Moreover, this approach would make auto-enrollment more successful if it can be operationalized, since no additional premium would be required.
Conclusion
The current situation presents an opportunity to replace the Affordable Care Act with a more sustainable bipartisan law. But repeal must wait until a consensus is built around a replacement plan. Not doing so – starting with repeal and delay – threatens to destabilize the individual market and harm not only those who receive subsidies from the ACA, but also everyone who now purchases insurance in the individual market.
Estimates show that premiums would jump at least 20 percent and cause 4.3 million to lose health insurance as soon as next year, and that’s nothing compared to the damage that would be inflicted if a replacement plan subsequently failed to emerge. The current version of repeal through reconciliation, leaving in place the ACA’s insurance market reforms, would nearly destroy the individual market if its provisions took effect, causing 30 million people in total to lose health insurance, leaving more uninsured than before the ACA.
Fixing the ACA is important, but replacing it with a durable plan to make health coverage broadly affordable will take time and constructive bipartisan collaboration.
You must be logged in to post a comment.